Fiscal impact reports (FIRs) are prepared by the Legislative Finance Committee (LFC) for standing finance
committees of the NM Legislature. The LFC does not assume responsibility for the accuracy of these reports
if they are used for other purposes.
Current FIRs (in HTML & Adobe PDF formats) are a vailable on the NM Legislative Website (legis.state.nm.us).
Adobe PDF versions include all attachments, whereas HTML versions may not. Previously issued FIRs and
attachments may be obtained from the LFC in Suite 101 of the State Capitol Building North.
F I S C A L I M P A C T R E P O R T
SPONSOR Griego
DATE TYPED 2/15/05
HB
SHORT TITLE Telecommunication Provider Competition
SB 672
ANALYST Rosen
APPROPRIATION
Appropriation Contained Estimated Additional Impact Recurring
or Non-Rec
Fund
Affected
FY05
FY06
FY05
FY06
NFI
NFI
(Parenthesis ( ) Indicate Expenditure Decreases)
Duplicates HB750
SOURCES OF INFORMATION
LFC Files
Responses Received From
Economic Development Department (EDD)
Attorney General’s Office (AGO)
Public Regulation Commission (PRC)
General Services Department (GSD)
Qwest
SUMMARY
Synopsis of Bill
Senate Bill 672 amends, repeals and enacts various sections of the New Mexico Telecommunica-
tions Act (NMTA) to change the way the state regulates telecommunications and protect con-
sumers and small businesses. This bill deletes or modifies key sections of NMTA designed to
promote competition in telecommunications markets.
Section 1 amends the Definition Section of NMTA to delete any reference to “competitive tele-
communications service”, “effective competition”, and “noncompetitive telecommunications
service” because Section 4 of the bill repeals the statute (current Section 63-9A-8) that sets out a
regulatory process and consequences of a PRC determination that a particular service, in a par-
ticular geographic area is subject to “effective competition”.
pg_0002
Senate Bill 672 -- Page 2
Section 2 adds new language dictating the regulatory procedure PRC will employ in regulating
rates for retail public telecommunications services. This replaces the current procedure set out in
Section 63-9A-8, which is repealed in Section 3, by which PRC determines on a service by ser-
vice and market by market basis whether a service is subject to “effective competition”. The
process is as follows: (1) Rates for basic residential and business local exchange service will be
set or modified in accordance with the incumbent local exchange carrier’s alternative form of
regulation (“AFOR”); (2) Decreases in retail business services, other than basic business local
exchange service, will be effective three days after they are provided to PRC with no possibility
of PRC review; (3) Decreases in retail residential services, other than basic residential local ex-
change service, will be effective three days after provision to PRC and posting to the telecom-
munications company’s public web site with no possibility of PRC review; (4) Increases in retail
services, other than basic business and residential service, will be in accordance with the AFOR.
Rates for local exchange services must cover the average variable cost for the provision of ser-
vice; however, there is no similar requirement for covering the costs of non-local exchange ser-
vices. The current prohibition in Section 63-9A-8 of cross-subsidization of competitive services
by non-competitive services is repealed in Section 3 of the bill. In Subsection 3E, the telecom-
munications company is specifically given the right to offer or discontinue offering special in-
centives, discounts, packaged offerings, temporary rate waiver or other promotions or to offer
individual contracts.
Section 3 repeals Section 63-9A-8 NMSA 1978, the “Effective Competition” section of NMTA.
Under the current system, as reflected in Section 63-9A-8, PRC is given the responsibility and
authority to determine whether an individual service is subject to “effective competition” in a
relevant market area and upon a finding of such, “modify, reduce or eliminate rules, regulations
and other requirements applicable to the provision of such service, including the fixing and de-
termining of specific rates, tariffs or fares”. Certain statutory considerations are to be applied by
PRC in making the determination whether a individual services are subject to effective competi-
tion: (1) the extent to which services are reasonably available from alternate providers in the
relevant market area; (2) the ability of alternate providers to make functionally equivalent or sub-
stitute services readily available at competitive rates, terms and conditions and (3) existing eco-
nomic or regulatory barriers. As stated above, there is also a provision in 63-9A-8 prohibiting
cross-subsidization of competitive services by non-competitive services. In the process and
scope of the current statutory provision, PRC, after notice and hearing, considers whether there is
effective competition for a particular service in a particular market area. Interested parties have
access to relevant data and are able to cross-examine witnesses and assumptions in a record-
based hearing. Under the current system, as reflected in Section 63-9A-8, the burden of proof is
on the telecommunications company to prove that there is effective competition. These proce-
dures and the determination of competition by PRC, on a case-by-case basis, would be repealed
under this bill.
Significant Issues
According to PRC, by repealing the effective competition statute this bill assumes there is effec-
tive competition for all services (except basic residential and business service) in all areas of the
state and, by legislative mandate, removes PRC and other interested parties (such as AGO) and
competitors (such as competitive local exchange carriers (CLECs)) from having a role in the
regulation of those services.
pg_0003
Senate Bill 672 -- Page 3
PRC indicates there is some question as to which telecommunications companies are covered by
the proposed new procedures in Section 2. Although rural telecommunications carriers and mid-
size carriers have their own sections of the statute, the definition in NMTA is broad enough to
cover them and they may be implicated because this would be a later enacted statutory provision.
PRC notes only incumbent carriers such as Qwest have AFORs. It is difficult to ascertain what
procedure and what timing would be applicable to interexchange carriers (IXC’s) and CLECs if
they wish to raise their rates. This is particularly true in light of the fact that PRC already has
rules that include timing, procedure and effective dates for IXC’s and CLEC’s proposed rate in-
creases.
According to PRC, only in the situation where incumbent local exchange carriers are wholesale
providers and retail competitors is there a danger of cross-subsidization of competitive services
by monopoly services. The provision in the statute that provides that local exchange services
(which are often the monopoly services) must cover the average variable cost does not prevent
cross-subsidization of competitive services. Average variable cost is not a term of art and is not
defined in the bill, thus there may be subjective ideas of what those costs would be.
PRC reports Qwest has a current AFOR that addresses such issues of packaged offerings, special
incentives, waivers and individual contracts that are essentially de-regulated in Subsection 2E of
this bill. However, in contrast to this bill, the AFOR imposes procedural, notice, unbundling and
bundling restrictions and cost coverage requirements. Subsection 2E would give a local tele-
communications company carte blanche to price these offerings on a case by case basis for dif-
ferent markets, different customers, and different situations, thereby potentially putting the cap-
tive monopoly customer and the potential competitor at a disadvantage. This subsection is also
in potential conflict with Section 63-9A-9 which governs the regulation of individual contracts to
facilitate competition.
Business and residential customers get no notice of potential increases in rates and only residen-
tial customers get minimal notice of decreases if they check the company’s website. The three-
day filing of a price list does not allow PRC to verify that decreases in rates cover costs (see
above). In addition, there is no provision for PRC, a customer or a competitor to challenge the
proposed rates as being below costs, anti-competitive or not just and reasonable.
According to AGO, this bill creates a regulatory environment that could undermine the growth of
competitors to Qwest. If this bill results in predatory pricing, the practice of providing services
at prices that are low enough to drive competitors out of a market, it could create a de facto mo-
nopoly. Once a competitor is driven from the market, the remaining monopoly provider of the
service has much greater ability and incentive to neglect investment and raise prices. Such a
situation is common in cases where a company controls an essential facility needed for service
provision, such as the telecommunication network’s central offices.
AGO notes generally, the following elements must exist to constitute predatory pricing:
The predator must have market power (power to unilaterally decrease or increase its
prices, or terms of service). In telecommunications, market power is conferred by virtue
of controlling the network’s “central offices.”
The predator must charge prices that fall bellow a predatory price standard.
pg_0004
Senate Bill 672 -- Page 4
AGO believes telecommunications market conditions and regulation determine that prices must
usually be below the “Long Run Incremental Costs” or “Total Service Long Run Incremental
Costs.” For example in New Mexico, the retail rate for POTS is $12.50 per line. However, to
obtain access to the infrastructure necessary to supply POTS, a competitor would have to pay a
wholesale rate of approximately $16.00 per line. Normally, there must be a reasonable expecta-
tion that the predator will be able to recoup its losses after its predation ends (e.g. after competi-
tors are driven out of the market).
AGO indicates predatory pricing is a particularly difficult type of conduct to prove in the tele-
communications industry. As previously discussed, the industry is characterized by substantial
joint and common costs, which are difficult to assign to particular services. The economic cost
tests used to determine predatory pricing, such as Average Variable Costs and Log Run Incre-
mental Costs, are difficult to apply to many types of telecommunications prices. This is espe-
cially true where the term “average variable costs” can be used without precision. Since the cur-
rent bill does not define “average variable costs” it is impossible to determine exactly what costs
the drafter intends to address in the bill. Passage of this bill could also result in litigation be-
cause of the arguable vagueness of undefined terms in the bill.
AGO reports, as a general matter, many of the definitions in this bill may potentially conflict
with definitions found in the Federal Telecommunications Act of 1996. The bill’s definition of
ILEC would apply only to Qwest.
According to AGO, deleting §63-9A-8 NMSA (1978) will eliminate a key portion of New Mex-
ico’s laws designed to promote competition in telecommunications markets, removing PRC’s
ability to make determinations of effective competition. Currently the PRC is authorized to
make specific, market-by-market determinations of “effective competition.” Such authority is
important because it recognizes that providing service in a place like Cuchillo, NM, is different
from providing service in Albuquerque. This section also prohibits “cross subsidization” of
competitive telecommunications services with services deemed non-competitive. The practical
effects of such a deletion would mean that an ILEC such as Qwest could use revenues obtained
from its “captive costumers” to subsidize services in markets that may have more competition.
Such a situation would make it impossible for PRC to create a “level playing field” for effective
competition.
PERFORMANCE IMPLICATIONS
Indeterminate
FISCAL IMPLICATIONS
Indeterminate.
ADMINISTRATIVE IMPLICATIONS
Indeterminate
CONFLICT, DUPLICATION, COMPANIONSHIP, RELATIONSHIP
Duplicates HB750
pg_0005
Senate Bill 672 -- Page 5
TECHNICAL ISSUES
PRC indicates the title of the bill does not accurately reflect the content of the bill, which repeals
the Effective Competition statute (Section 63-9A-8).
AGO indicates many of the definitions in this bill may potentially conflict with definitions found
in the Federal Telecommunications Act of 1996.
OTHER SUBSTANTIVE ISSUES
GSD reports the bill will allow for competition in the “business customer environment.”
PRC questions whether sufficient competition exists in all services in all parts of the state to en-
sure the procedures set out in this bill will not conflict with the purpose of NMTA to promote
competition.
Qwest sees robust state-wide competition for wireless phone service and believes this “pricing
flexibility” bill will allow Qwest to better compete in the market place.
ALTERNATIVES
PRC suggests changing the title of the bill to indicate it repeals the Effective Competition statute
(Section 63-9A-8).
PRC suggest streamlining or revising current PRC procedures associated with the Determination
of Effective Competition rather than repealing the entire statute.
WHAT WILL BE THE CONSEQUENCES OF NOT ENACTING THIS BILL.
Status quo maintained, with continued PRC oversight and consumer protection provisions to de-
termine effective competition in the marketplace.
JR/lg